Fiscal stimulus does not necessarily mean large government

There was an interesting if not ego-centric interchange last week involving the New Keynesian economist Paul Krugman and others about whether the sort of macroeconomic policy positions one takes is more motivated by ideological motives (about the desirable size of government) rather than being evidence-based. Apparently, if you support austerity it is because you really just want smaller government and vice versa. This is an oft-stated claim made by conservatives. That if you support fiscal stimulus and government regulation that you are automatically in favour of big (intrusive) government. The point is not valid. Whether one supports a larger proportional government or smaller is a separate matter to understanding how the monetary system functions and the capacities and options available to the government. Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) provides the basis for that understanding but not a prescription for a particular size of government.

To begin, there is no necessary correspondence between support for fiscal stimulus and one’s perception of how large the government sector should be as a proportion of the overall economy.

Continuous fiscal deficits of some proportion may be necessary irrespective of the size of government. To argue otherwise is to misunderstand the role of fiscal deficits in the monetary system.

The dispute between Krugman and Austrian School economist Russ Roberts started a while ago. Roberts, from Stanford cites his influences as Gary Becker, Friedrich Hayek and Milton Friedman, an unsavoury trio if there ever was.

He wrote in an article (October 11, 2011) – The evidence for Keynesian economics – that:

Krugman is a Keynesian because he wants bigger government. I’m an anti-Keynesian because I want smaller government.

Now, clearly one’s perspective on the size of government cannot be prescribed by any body of theory. It is a misconception to think that mainstream textbook economic theory proves the government should be ‘small’. There is no proof to that end.

Orthodox economic theory, in fact, has nothing to say about the optimal size of government.

Further, there is nothing “Keynesian” that dictates a preference for a particular size of government.

I discuss the vexed use of the term ‘Keynesian’ in this blog – Those bad Keynesians are to blame.

Paul Krugman has defined the term to suit himself. In his New York Times article (November 3, 2009) –
On not listening
– he had claimed that:

The position held by Keynesians … is that fiscal stimulus is necessary only under certain special conditions. Namely, when you’re up against the zero lower bound, and conventional monetary policy is useless, fiscal stimulus may be your best option.

In his latest entreaty into the subject (June 6, 2015) – Why Am I A Keynesian? – he repeats that construction in a defensive way to disabuse readers of any notion that he supports “bigger governnment”:

If I were, shouldn’t I be advocating permanent expansion rather than temporary measures? Shouldn’t I be for stimulus all the time, not only when we’re at the zero lower bound? When I do call for bigger government – universal health care, higher Social Security benefits – shouldn’t I be pushing these things as job-creation measures? (I don’t think I ever have). I think if you look at the record, I’ve always argued for temporary fiscal expansion, and only when monetary policy is constrained.

The essential point that Paul Krugman has been making about his own conception of what constitutes Keynesian thinking is that “recessions … [result from] … failures of aggregate demand” and that there is a role for governments to reverse those failures using monetary or fiscal policy.

But, in his view, “when the slump pushes rates down to zero, and that’s still not enough, any simple model I can think of says that fiscal expansion can be a useful supplement, while fiscal austerity makes a bad situation worse”.

So fiscal policy is only to be preferred when monetary policy is ineffective and that happens according to Krugman when there is a zero interest rate policy (ZIRP).

At times, Krugman has equated the ZIRP with the notion of a ‘liquidity trap’ to reinforce his Keynesian credentials.

I have written about the issue of the liquidity trap before. Please see the blogs – The on-going crisis has nothing to do with a supposed liquidity trap and Whether there is a liquidity trap or not is irrelevant – for further discussion.

Paul Krugman abuses the meaning of the ‘liquidity trap’ and his version is not rooted in the work of Keynes. He is among a group of economists that articulated the same position during the early months of the GFC that the economy was presenting a special case which they deemed to be – the “liquidity trap” case.

Accordingly, they argued, that when an economy enters a liquidity trap monetary policy loses its capacity to influence aggregate demand via interest rate changes and only fiscal policy (deficits) can be effective in reviving real GDP growth.

It is this association that allows these economists to identify themselves as Keynesian or New Keynesian and many so-called ‘progressive’ economists fit into this category, however ill-defined it might be.

I explain in detail in this blog – Whether there is a liquidity trap or not is irrelevant – why this appeal to Keynes is invalid.

In summary (you should read the whole blog if you are curious), the liquidity trap does not require a zero interest rate to become operational.

The Keynesian link is usually made by appealing to a section in Keynes’ 1936 book – The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money – specifically Chapter 15, Section II.

Keynes talked about liquidity preference in Chapter 13 of the General Theory where he introduced the transactions-motive for holding cash balances. That is, people will hold cash to allow them to purchases goods and services on a daily basis.

In Chapter 15, he expounded on this in more detail and came up with several distinct motives for holding cash. One such motive – the Speculative-motive – was central to the way he thought about uncertainty.

In the Classical theory, money was just a transactional commodity with no special characteristics other than to ease exchange. People exchange in real terms (based on perceptions of real use values) and the introduction of money was of no particular import to those valuations. It just eased the so-called problem of barter where the double-coincidence of wants might be absent (the baker doesn’t want her plumbing fixed and the plumber prefers fruit!).

But for Keynes, money was special and “plays a part of its own and affects motives and decisions and is, in short, one of the operative factors in the situation, so that the course of events cannot be predicted, either in the long period or in the short period, without a knowledge of the behaviour of money ebtween the first state and the last” (taken from his book “On the Theory of a Monetary Economy”, page 216).

What that means for our purposes here is that money serves as a temporal link between present and the unknowable future.

What does that mean? Keynes said that money can act to “lull our disquietude” about the uncertainty of the future. By holding money we do not commit to purchase. Instead we hold liquidity until we are more certain of things.

So when there is rising unemployment or other sources of uncertainty, more people will hold money as a safety measure and refrain from spending.

In the Chapter 17 (Section III) of the General Theory, Keynes wrote:

Unemployment develops, that is to say, because people want the moon; – men cannot be employed when the object of desire (i.e. money) is something which cannot be produced and the demand for which cannot be readily choked off. There is no remedy but to persuade the public that green cheese is practically the same thing and to have a green cheese factory (i.e. a central bank) under public control.

In other words, the increased demand for money to ease uncertainty doesn’t produce any real goods and services which would employ people, unlike, say, the increased demand for motor cars.

So money is a special commodity.

It is the most liquid asset available but because it earns no interest (unlike a bond) there is an opportunity cost in holding it. So people will hold more cash when interest rates fall rather than when they rise.

Central banks influence interest rates by conducting ‘open market operations’ – they exchange government bonds with the private sector.

Keynes argued that monetary authorities can normally:

… purchase (or sell) bonds in exchange for cash by bidding the price of bonds up (or down) in the market by a modest amount; and the larger the quantity of cash which they seek to create (or cancel) by purchasing (or selling) bonds and debts, the greater must be the fall (or rise) in the rate of interest.

He is referring to ‘open market operations’ here which have been normal liquidity management operations of central banks. Please read my blog – Budget deficits do not cause higher interest rates – for more discussion on this point.

But there is a point where people will only wish to hold cash and will eschew the purchase of bonds, thus rendering the capacity of the central bank to modify the interest rate ineffective.

And in that sense, monetary policy becomes ineffective as a means of altering the level of total spending in the economy.

This leads to our understanding of the liquidity trap as developed by Keynes. At some point, people form the expectation that the future prices of all income-earning assets (stores of wealth) are at their maximum and that any purchases of those assets would result in a capital losses.

This coincides with a situation where interest rates reach some low point (not necessarily zero). The expectation of capital loss is based on the inverse relationship between interest rates and bond prices explained in the blog cited above.

So everyone holds cash rather than bonds because they consider interest rates are so low they can only rise which means that purchasing bonds at existing market prices would guarantee a capital loss as their prices fell.

The central bank then cannot push rates lower and if aggregate demand is deficient at that level of rates they allegedly lose their capacity to increase spending.

This is what Keynes call the ‘liquidity trap’.

You can see that this is not the same thing as a ZIRP chosen by the central bank. Krugman’s liquidity trap does not arise in the same way that Keynes’ trap does and it is wrong to claim an association with the latter concept.

Paul Krugman also argued that a Keynesian position is for “temporary” rather than “permanent” stimulus. The fiscal stimulus should only come at the zero interest rate. Which implies that normally he considers monetary policy should be given primacy and fiscal policy is a special case

Did Keynes have a preference for monetary policy?

Keynes’ earlier interests were associated with his perception that he was somehow directly extending the work of Alfred Marshall who had taught him about ‘money’ at Cambridge. Keynes sat in Marshall’s monetary classes in 1905.

He developed his monetary economics within a firm view that central banks should cooperate to maintain fixed exchange rates, a position he held until his death and which influenced the development of the Post World War II Bretton Woods system that operated until 1971.

In the early days of the Great Depression (around 1931) he firmly advocated the Bank of England to cut the discount rate (the rate it lends reserves to the commercial banks) to stimulate credit creation in the banking system.

The so-called ‘cheap-money’ policy suggested that he favoured monetary policy as the principle weapon for counter-stabilisation.

He also advocated controlling longer term investment rates to ensure they were low enough to stimulate spending. He celebrated the British government’s decision in 1932, for example, to cut the interest rate on outstanding War Bonds, which allowed the Bank of England to reduce long-term interest rates generally.

In the The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes XXI, which covered “Activities 1931-9: World Crises and Policies in Britain and America”, he wrote (Page 395):

The Bank of England and the Treasury had a great success at the time of the conversion of the War Loan. But it is possible that they still underrate the extent of their powers. With the existing control over the exchanges which has revolutionised the technical position, and with the vast resources at the disposal of the authorities through the Bank of England, the Exchange Equalisation Fund, and other funds under the control of the Treasury, it lies within their power, by the exercise of the moderation, the gradualness, and the discreet handling of the market of which they have shown themselves to be masters, to make the long- term rate of interest what they choose within reason.

He also advocated the use of “tap issue” system of debt issuance, which dominated public debt management until the neo-liberal era began. Accordingly, the government would announce the yield (interest rate) it was prepared to pay on different debt maturities and then the private market could buy whatever volume of bonds they chose, the central bank filling any shortfalls in desired revenue.

This system effectively allowed the government to control all yields. This system was abandoned in the 1980s in Australia when the Government decided that it would move to a full auction system whereby the government would set the volume of cash desired from the bond issue and the private sector would determine the interest it required to earn to supply that much cash.

This new system gave the impression that the private bond markets were in charge. But it was just a voluntary choice to provide corporate welfare.

Keynes was important because he broke with the Classical tradition by advocating a central role for a central bank which was to advance general well-being and demonstrated how ‘money’ was a crucial commodity in its own right in an environment of endemic uncertainty.

So there is some merit in considering that Keynes’ early work was focused not on counter-stabilising policies in a crisis but rather setting in place an institutional structure that would provide for stability in domestic and international monetary conditions.

He also believed that large-scale public works, for example, were an important policy intervention that governments could use to break a recession arising from a deficiency of private spending.

He clearly showed that the capitalist monetary system could become trapped at production levels which generated mass unemployment and required an external spending intervention from government.

Does this mean that he was supporting fiscal deficits in the same way as Modern Monetary Theory (MMT)? Not really, he considered that the expansion on the public expenditure side would via the multiplier expand output and employment and tax revenue.

In his Essays in Persuasion (1933), he discusses the impact of the automatic stabilisers on tax receipts and spending.

He writes that “We have reached a point where a considerable proportion of every further decline in the national income is visited on the Exchequer through the agency of the dole and the decline in the yield of the taxes. it is natural, therefore, that the benefit of measures to increase the national income should largely accrue to the Exchequer”.

He then wrote:

If we apply this reasoning to the projects for loan-expenditure which are receiving support today in responsible quarters, we see that it is a complete mistake to believe that there is a dilemma between schemes for increasing employment and schemes for balancing the Budget, – that we must go slowly and cautiously with the former for fear of injuring the latter. Quite the contrary. There is no possibility of balancing the Budget except by increasing the national income, which is much the same thing as increasing employment.

So he thought austerity was bad if the government wanted to “balance the budget” but that fiscal stimulus would not undermine that aim.

So there is some truth in Paul Krugman’s notion that being “Keynesian” meant that you advocated temporary fiscal deficits.

That, of-course, sets his position apart from the Functional Finance principles developed by Abba Lerner which Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) is more closely aligned with.

Functional finance says that government should always be guided in its policy choices by how effective they in influencing national income and employment.

The concept of a ‘balanced budget’ becomes irrelevant and should never be a goal of the government.

Please read my blog – Functional finance and modern monetary theory – for more discussion on this point.

In this conception, permanent fiscal stimulus may be the most appropriate policy action if non-government spending (and saving) decisions leave a spending gap – defined in terms of the level of spending required to produce enough employment to satisfy the desires of the available labour supply.

There is every reason to believe that continuous fiscal deficits are required, especially when external deficits are the norm.

It might be argued that these continuous deficits are not stimulus measures. That is, a fiscal stimulus might only mean a discretionary increase in the deficit.

That would be a difficult argument to maintain. Stimulus just means adding to expenditure and a continuous deficit continuously supports spending – preferably at desirable full employment levels.

Paul Krugman is in the ‘balanced budget over the cycle’ camp which is at odds with functional finance (and MMT) but not necessary at odds with the early writings of Keynes.

Where Krugman fall foul of Keynes though is in his New Keynesian belief that it is the rigidity of wages and prices that separates Classical from Keynesian theory. That is another blog – but I touch on it in this blog – Those bad Keynesians are to blame – among others.

Conclusion

A ZIRP situation may, by definition, reduce the capacity of the central bank to influence effective demand in the economy any further. But it is not the same state that Keynes considered rendered monetary policy ineffective.

I should add that MMT also does not automatically bias one to thinking that government should be relatively large. Small government advocates would be wise to understand MMT principles given they apply to monetary economies irrespective of the size of government.

Some MMT proponents that I know support larger public sector provision, while others support a greater role for the private sector. But we all agree on the way that the monetary system operates and the capacities that the currency-issuer holds in that system to further the well-being of the population.

That is enough for today!

(c) Copyright 2015 William Mitchell. All Rights Reserved.

This Post Has 34 Comments

  1. I enjoyed that.

    It is where the neoliberal framing comes in. To frame the debate to stop government interventions. Most politicians haven’t a clue but they know what size of state they want.

    So they trot out their delusional metaphors that feed into assumptions in order to brainwash their voting base.

  2. Plus MMT (the descriptive side) is just true whatever.
    It just removes “we can’t afford it” once you realise government spends first and taxes and borrows back what spent. And how banking actually works.

  3. Bill’s basic point, i.e. that “fiscal stimulus does not necessarily mean large government” is quite correct of course. That it’s even necessary to explain that simple point to Ivy League economists like Russ Roberts of Stanford is a tragedy and helps explain the catastrophic levels of unemployment in recent years.

    When it comes to stupidity and economic illiteracy, no university comes close to Harvard (Rogoff, Reinhart etc). But seems Stanford is a runner up.

  4. There is every reason to believe that continuous fiscal deficits are required, especially when external deficits are the norm.
    Continuous fiscal deficits being being required is the result of a tendency for the private sector to net save, which is indicative of a policy failure (such as interest rates being too high).

    Continuous deficits may be desirable based on a range of other factors. But when they’re the only option, it’s safe to assume something’s gone terribly wrong!

  5. Thank you, Dr. Mitchell … great

    Any thoughts as to why people/institutions are still parting with money for negative yields?

    Uncertainty, deflation, risk allocation, default? … What is the “c,” the carrying costs? Why is the “q” (liquidity premium), perhaps negative?

    Might be an occasion to extend Post Keynesian theory to account for negative yields – that is, what is the function of such assets when a taxes-drive-money approach and essential properties of money features are theoretically fertile? …

    I’m thinking – Ch. 17 of the GT – that the second differentia of money, the elasticity of substitution, might offer a compelling reason in that other “rent elements” are being distinguished and other assets are trying to be stimulated – set me straight though!

    Thanks again! … (Apologies if this is totally off or crazy)

  6. Setting aside the historical, academic and theoretical discussions.

    It appears, at least to me, that none of the chattering class has any intention of addressing reality.

  7. Dear Bill

    I agree with your argument that MMT is neutral with regard to the size of the government, but I would add the qualification that advocacy of the minimal state is incompatible with MMT. In a minimal state, total government expenditures may not be more than 4% of GDP. Consequently, if the deficit required for full employment is 8% of GDP, then the minimal state will have to be expanded, so it is no longer minimal.

    Regards. James

  8. A year or two ago, Krugman was on Newsnight with a couple of Tories. In a discussion of austerity, the Tories admitted that one of the reasons that they at least supported austerity was to shrink the state. Krugman then said to them that that was another issue, implicitly distinguishing it from austerity. But that was about all he had to say on the matter on that occasion.

  9. Bill, I think the crux of your argument lies in your use of the term “necessarily”. In my view, it is likely though of course not necessary that a fiscal stimulus will involve a larger rather than a smaller state. You are right, of course, that fiscal stimulation does not necessarily carry the baggage of an enlargement of the state. But current neocons equate the two in the sense that doing the former involves doing the latter, implying that there is some causal link between the two. Hence, their argument that shrinking the state necessitates cutting government spending.

  10. I should add that while it may be true that state shrinkage involves a decrement in government spending, however small, it does not follow that any fiscal stimulus package is necessarily involved. Hence, their argument is invalid; indeed, I would go so far as to contend that the conclusion they want to draw is a non sequitur.

  11. “Consequently, if the deficit required for full employment is 8% of GDP, then the minimal state will have to be expanded, so it is no longer minimal.”
    Negative income tax?

  12. There is a world of difference between Fiscal stimulus does not necessarily mean large
    government and MMT does not necessarily mean large government.Cut taxes and you
    will increase fiscal stimulus without increasing the size of the government but
    delivering the MMT commitment of a guarenteed job for all at a living wage without
    increasing the size of the government? It would certainly require enormous
    subsidy and regulation of the private sector.
    Of course it does depend how you define a ‘living wage’ and if you are talking
    about theoretical economies or reality .

  13. “It would certainly require enormous
    subsidy and regulation of the private sector.”
    ?? JG are govt jobs. Labour market regs can be abolished after JG.

  14. bob if JG jobs are govt jobs then MMT would mean larger government.
    if they were guarenteed at at a living wage at a time of mass unemployment
    mass underemployment and mass lower than living wage onerous employment
    then it would mean large government out of neccesity. Perhaps not in Japan.

  15. By the way I am very much in favour of large government but still
    within a mixed economy.

  16. Dear Kevin Harding (at 2015/06/10 at 6:23)

    You have to ask yourself: where are the unemployed now (in lieu of a Job Guarantee) and where would they be in the event of a Job Guarantee?

    The answer is: Public Sector irrespective (in most nations).

    The size of the public sector would not change much except that the unemployed would be productively employed within the public sector rather than doing nothing.

    best wishes
    bill

  17. Dear Phil (at 2015/06/10 at 4:40)

    Perhaps. But he would not have endorsed Modern Monetary Theory given his penchant for fixed exchange rate arrangements and international currencies.

    I also do not think he would have given up his emphasis on monetary policy.

    best wishes
    bill

  18. that’s what I am saying bill that the JG would increase the public sector.
    If it is set at a living wage when in most countries the private sector cannot
    provide large amounts of the population with a living wage it would significantly
    increase the private sector.
    It does of course depend on what you mean by a living wage and if you think we
    are currently producing the necessities that comprise a god living for all.I absolutely
    share the goal of work and a decent living standards for all but do not think that can be
    achieved without a larger public sector and even then it is going to take some time
    to deliver after all it has never been achieved yet.

  19. sorry typo I think guaranteeing a living wage JG would significantly increase
    the public sector which I favour but by more targeted public works to deliver
    what makes a good living.

  20. I tend to be a little cynical about the neoliberals when they say that we need smaller government.
    I remember Thatcher telling us that we did not need the nanny state, that there was no such thing as society, only individuals and their families. The subtext was the resentment of the losses to the rich of their massive rent seeking ventures which had occurred during the post war consensus. The seventies was the zenith of equality, and it was time to reverse it. Wealthy families, bank and corporations were receiving much less of the economic!ic surplus than they had enjoyed in previous decades.
    This was not because government had got larger, but because through government spending and taxation they had redistributed the wealth as described above.
    Government is just as large and controlling as it was in the progressive era, it is only different in where it directs wealth. The many state, instead of working towards full employment, allows a build up of debt and poverty, and than bails out the banks.
    Instead of providing services, it subsidises rent seeking companies in the UK now, to provide health and social care.
    Governance is all pervasive and directive, but favours the rent seeker, the finance industry and other profiteers, instead of citizens and workers.

  21. Dear Kevin Harding (at 2015/06/10 at 8:05)

    You said:

    that’s what I am saying bill that the JG would increase the public sector.

    I think you missed my point. The unemployed (in most countries) are already in the public sector. So shifting them from being jobless on income support to working in a Job Guarantee hardly scales the public sector up much.

    best wishes
    bill

  22. Bill, that’s dubious. I doubt many unemployed people regard themselves as in the public sector, and I’m certain they’re not officially counted as working in the public sector.

    Most people would measure public sector size by GDP anyway, and a JG would be a significantly bigger proportion of GDP than what’s currently spent.

  23. Dear Aidan (at 2015/06/10 at 14:11)

    Who said anything about the unemployed being “officially counted as working in the public sector”? I just said they were IN the public sector (on income support) because they were not being utilised in the private sector.

    best wishes
    bill

  24. I take your point bill .The unemployed having their income provided by the state are
    monetarily in the public sector along with the pensioners and those in full time education.
    What proportion on average of the OECD countries populations do pay more in taxes
    than they receive in services and welfare?
    It seems the current standard of living is dependent on large government.I think if
    your goal is to achieve decent living standards for all it is not large enough.

  25. Nice try, Bill, but small government advocates wouldn’t regard them as in the public sector. Though many would want the government to stop paying them anyway.

    Anyway, it will, at least initially, cost more to have them on a JG, so in financial terms the government will still be biggger.

  26. “Anyway, it will, at least initially, cost more to have them on a JG, so in financial terms the government will still be biggger.”
    Stop thinking about money. Start thinking about resources.

  27. Hi

    I’d like to thank Larry for his comment at 20:41 on Tuesday the 9th of June 2015; I searched for the Newsnight clip and found it on YouTube.

    The date was 30th May 2012 and the clip is less than 9 minutes in length. I’m not sure if a YouTube link is allowed here, so apologies to Bill if they’re not. The URL is https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=_r-AKruzmkk

    Jeremy Paxman introduced the guests as “John Molton, the venture capitalist and chairman of Better Capital, and Andrea Leadsom, a Conservative MP who previously worked in finance for 25 years”.

    (Two years after this appearance, Andrea Leadsom would for 13 months hold the post of the Economic Secretary to the Treasury, which is the fifth most senior ministerial role in the Treasury.)

    It is John Molton who is first to say, when he comes into the debate at 3 mins 05 secs, that the State should be smaller: “The issue about austerity here is really we have too large a State.” He then says that if you want growth you need “a larger private sector, not a larger public sector”. Andrea Leadsom chimes in with “Mmm. Exactly”.

    They later echo each other when John Milton says “Those jobs will be generated when people move from the public sector to the private sector.” “Yes”, says Andrea Leadsom.

    You may remember that in 2012 the UK hosted the Olympics and Paralympics, and George Osborne was very strongly booed at the former. At the time, the Conservatives were widely seen in a negative light over the recession, and negative cuts, but sometime over the next few years the public moved on from having a go at the Conservatives over the economy and instead seemed to buy in to the idea that the economy is almost mended, and that this is due to their willingness to suffer cutbacks (still cheerily labelled as ‘savings’ by the BBC and other television and printed news outlets) and shoulder the burden of ‘hard work’.

    The public have, during the past 7 years since the crunch/crash, become very money-oriented, and even talk of cuts to disability welfare or sickness welfare falls on deaf ears. Compassion and righteous anger don’t rise up often, but self-righteousness based on ‘I’m hard-working and so should you be’ can often be heard/read. This has directly followed on from the politicians sloganeering, which they have linked with ‘austerity’, ‘hard-work’ and ‘economic recovery’. The public are more convinced than ever that ‘hard work’ is the only thing that will get us out of an economic downturn, and many of them can be heard/read angrily and haughtily wielding the whip against their fellow citizens, having personally taken on the task of meting out discipline in this national endeavour of ‘recovery’.

    They are now more firmly than ever wedded to the idea that the government cannot and must not spend beyond its means. The public are utterly convinced that they generate the government’s money through working, and only then can the government spend it. This is so entrenched now that it is utterly beyond discussion – to attempt to challenge it only provokes strong anger (because you’re jeopardising the recovery of the good ship UK). This is why the Labour leadership contenders are now blethering on about surpluses – the public are utterly convinced of the household analogy and think that anything else constitutes ‘the magic money-tree’.

    I would go so far as to say that there has never been a stronger set of beliefs taken hold in the UK’s consciousness in my lifetime. IMO those who want to challenge ‘austerity’ in the UK need to not underestimate what has happened here.

  28. Jim you are so right about the extant of the challenge facing any kind of progressive
    politics in the uk.It is a catch 22 for labour they believe they cannot convince
    people of the need for government sector deficits and in failing to challenge any of the assumptions
    reinforce them in the minds in the electorate.
    This of course is an ideal scenario for right wing ideologues. Global financial crisis and
    austerity are counter intuitively a historic opportunity for them to shrink the state.
    It goes beyond fiscal stimulus and size of the government .It goes to the heart of the
    new faith in the god of the market which social democratic parties have bowed down to.
    That is why I think this post is so important.IF fiscal stimulus does not mean large government
    it will not serve the best interests of citizens.It is about knowing the price of everything
    and the value of nothing.
    Progressives struggle against the household anaolgy on public sector deficits is apart of
    a larger struggle against the blind faith in the markets.It should embrace a strong government
    sector within a mixed economy.Arguing the government should use all its economic
    powers to spend,tax and regulate in the best interests of the majority of its citizens.
    They need large government.

  29. Jim, you are so right about the entrenchment of these historically incorrect understanding of what happened in history and no understanding of how the money system works. You can see this in the debate of Ron Paul Vs Paul Krugman in Ron Paul VS Paul Krugman 4-30-12 FULL Bloomberg: https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=WEoGKpnutyA. Krugman is much better than his opponents, especially this one.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Back To Top